An Example of Quantified Opinion
• John Vandivier
This article demonstrates the method of quantified opinion. Quantified opinion is a logic-based probabilistic method, a field of statistics, which constructs a statistical model from the opinions of individuals.
Quantified opinion is unique from something like a survey or poll because it is particularly meant to address extremely low sample sizes ( 1 < n < 5), and it is also meant to address immensely complex questions which are generally not a good fit for the usual kind of poll or survey.
While other articles on the website have discussed the theory of the method to varying degrees (at least here and here), this article will simply give an example of application without much theory. This example is also based on a real-life application which I used in a professional setting.
A group of political consultants is debating whether or not they should invest in a project. The project will temporarily increase their ability to earn revenue, but they need to determine a rational expectation for that increase.
The consultants agree:
- There will be some increase.
- The increase will be less than 100%.
- There are two levels of increased revenue: An optimal level and a maximum level. The optimum level considers the cost of the project, while the maximum level assumes a limitless spending budget. The maximum level is larger than the optimal level.
- The real cost of the project is somewhere between the optimal level and the maximum level.
- Let's call the optimal level increase P (because \"O\" looks like zero) and the maximum level increase M. Let's call the real level R.
- From assumptions 1 and 2, we know that 0 < P < 100%. The rational, or risk-minimizing, estimate for P is 50%.
- From assumptions 2 and 3, we know that P < M < 100%. The rational, or risk-minimizing, estimate for M is 75%.
- The rational, or risk-minimizing, estimate for R is 62.5%.
- Assuming that P is not 50%, the two equally rational next-best choices would be 25% and 75%. The distribution we are assuming is that there is an equal likelihood of any particular outcome in the range. Because the possible range is 0 < P < 1, we must rationally be 50% confident that .25 < P < .75.
- We could also say that we are 75% confident that 12.5% < P < 87.5%, etc ad infinitum.
- Intentionally bias the expert towards approval.
- Intentionally bias the expert away from overconfidence bias, which experts are known to exhibit.
- This is how markets work. Actors maximize their income and it empirically turns out that this does not usually go hand in hand with production of misinformation. It can in some cases, but the market norm is that production of good information leads to efficiency.
- This is how financial investment works. Actors maximize return on investment by making wagers as carefully as possible using the best information possible. Don't view the actor as the business which may disseminate bad information. The expert undergoing the quantified opinion process is more like the investor acting on available information rather than the business creating favorable information.
- PredictIt uses betting to predict political events, such as elections. They seem to be having some success, although I don't have specific data at the moment.
- BitBet is a bitcoin-based enterprise through which you can bet on anything. All bets take the form of \"Yes\" vs \"No\" and a series of technical rules particular to each individual bet are made public. If those rules are fulfilled, the yeas win. Otherwise the nays win. I have used the site several times and anecdotally it is extremely precise. One problem is that the bets are taken over a wide window of time, so that sometimes the late betters have significantly more information. This problem is solved because early betters earn multipliers on their wagers, but the effect remains that the outcome is often very similar to the final estimation, even if it was very different at an earlier time.